Connect with us

Business

If you cough, you’re off

Published

on

Unlock the Editor’s Digest for free

What do you do if you turn up to work and find yourself sitting next to someone with a streaming nose, a hacking cough and other signs of a full-blown cold or flu?

This question arose the other day when I arrived at the start of a day-long business conference and sat at a table where another attendee plonked his loudly snivelling self on the seat beside me. 

Advertisement

As he spluttered and honked away, all hope of concentrating on what was being said on stage evaporated. Visions swam of the shattered work schedule, the missed appointments and the headachy days in bed that his pathogen-spraying presence threatened.

I turned and fixed him with what I hoped was a meaningful glare each time he coughed, then sighed, loudly and repeatedly, none of which he noticed. Eventually, I packed up my things and moved to a distant table. 

In the coffee break a bit later, I spotted a man who had also been sitting near the snuffling offender and said: “That chap at your table sounds as if he has an awful cold.”

“Yeah, I told him to move away,” the man replied. “I’ve got a board meeting this week and I can’t afford to get sick.”

Advertisement

I stared at him, awed by this forthright approach and mildly livid for failing to adopt it myself.

Back in the office, with flu season bearing down and Covid rates rising again, I kept thinking about this incident and wondering why, years after the pandemic made us hyper-aware of workplace contagion, we can still be so useless at handling it.

I suspect there is a need for a constant reminder of one of the first rules of office etiquette: if you cough, you’re off.

As far as humanly possible, this should be the default option for infected workers. Coming in to work with spreadable germs is not just bad manners. It’s also bad for productivity if it fells others. 

Advertisement

This should be completely obvious. Alas, it is not because too many bosses set a rotten example by coming to work when ill themselves in the misguided belief that showing up at all times enhances productivity. In fact, researchers have shown for years that sickness presenteeism, or working at less than full speed because of illness, can cut productivity by a third or more — and can also be more costly than absenteeism. 

There are of course legitimate exceptions to the cough-off rule. A cough can last for weeks, long after infection levels should have subsided.

Also, if you fall mildly ill before an event that’s been months in the making, where hundreds of people are relying on your presence, it may be reasonable to guzzle Lemsip, keep your distance and hope for the best.

However, since most of us are not required to host the Oscars or get sworn in as US commander-in-chief, it is fine to stay home instead. 

Advertisement

I say all this as someone who has come to work unwell myself for fear of missing some big event or deadline. But that was a) idiotic and b) before the rise of hybrid working. If you are lucky enough to have the option of working from home, you can sate your Stakhanovite urges without unleashing microbial mayhem on office colleagues.

But remote work can present different problems. Before the pandemic struck, the data showed that people who did their jobs from home tended to work more days when ill than those who had to be in the office. As remote working rose, it sparked complaints that people felt obliged to stay on the clock when unwell. As many as 65 per cent of US workers polled said they had felt such pressure in 2021.

This is unfortunate. The first rule of getting over a cold quickly can be summed up in four words: “Get plenty of rest.” That means flaking out in front of the TV. Or lying in bed. Or wallowing in a hot bath. It does not mean spending hours answering emails, logging on to Zoom meetings and writing up reports.

Again, this should be obvious but again, it often is not. To be fair to overburdened managers, it is harder to figure out if an employee is overdoing it instead of resting if said worker is at home.

Advertisement

Harder, but, like so many sensible office behaviour rules, far from impossible. 

pilita.clark@ft.com

Source link

Advertisement
Continue Reading
Advertisement
Click to comment

You must be logged in to post a comment Login

Leave a Reply

Business

Soft landing vs no landing

Published

on

Soft landing vs no landing

This article is an on-site version of our Unhedged newsletter. Premium subscribers can sign up here to get the newsletter delivered every weekday. Standard subscribers can upgrade to Premium here, or explore all FT newsletters

Good morning. Nuclear energy stocks have soared to record highs on the back of big tech’s demand for green energy. Will this be the start of a new chapter for the technology? Or will regulation, accidents, and popular opionion get in the way? To adapt J. Robert Oppenheimer’s quoting of the Bhagavad Gita: “I am become uncertainty, ruler of markets.” Email us: robert.armstrong@ft.com and aiden.reiter@ft.com.

Soft landing vs no landing

Recently there has been some debate across the financial-economic punditocracy about whether we are experiencing a “soft landing” or a “no landing” scenario. In a soft landing, growth slows but recession is avoided, while inflation returns to a low and stable level. In a no landing scenario, growth doesn’t slow and inflation remains either a worry — volatile, and not quite down to target — or an outright problem.

The difference matters. In a no landing scenario, the Fed has to keep the policy rate relatively high, which squeezes the rate sensitive and cyclical parts of the economy, as well as indebted consumers. Anyone who owns longer-duration fixed income is likely to feel some pain, and in equities, sectors with inflation-hedging characteristics — materials, for example — will do better. 

Advertisement

For a long time Unhedged has felt very confident that growth was falling gently and inflation was all but over with. Even just a few weeks ago, we were pretty dismissive about the odds of no landing. But our confidence, it pains us to admit, is wavering a bit. And it appears we are not alone. In the latest Bank of America fund manager survey, no landing remains a tail risk, but the tail is twice as wide as it was a month ago:

A summary of the recent growth data that is forcing this rethink:

  • September’s stronger jobs report.

  • September’s strong retail report, which showed 5 per cent annualised growth and cemented an accelerating pattern: the three month average rate is now higher than the six month rate, which is higher than the 12 month rate.  

  • What we heard in the big banks’ earnings reports. JPMorgan’s CFO: “spending patterns [are] solid and consistent with the narrative that the consumer is on solid footing and consistent with the strong labour market and the current central case of a kind of no-landing scenario economically”; Bank of America CEO “[Consumer] payments were up 4 to 5 per cent year-over-year. The pace of year-to-year money movement has been steady since late summer . . . this activity is consistent with how customers are spending money in the 2016 to 2019 timeframe when the economy was growing, inflation was under control.”

  • Wages are growing at a 4 per cent clip that has not slowed since April. 

  • Markets’ increasing bullishness, which both reflects the economic growth and contributes to it. 

On the inflation side, there are a million ways to cut the data, but it is pretty clear that progress on inflation has slowed significantly; we have been stuck at 2.5 or 3 per cent for a few months now. Over at The Overshoot, Matt Klein gathers the various measures of CPI inflation with volatile components removed, and shows that 2024 looks a lot like 2023:

PCE inflation, which the Fed cares most about, is a bit better, but also appears to be stabilising a bit above target. The New York Fed’s model for the trend in PCE inflation is at 2.6 per cent:

Unhedged remains in the soft landing/inflation is over camp, and can point to various factors on both the growth side (manufacturing, housing, small business confidence) and the inflation side (shelter inflation finally coming down) to offset the uncomfortable warmth of recent data points. More importantly, zooming out, it simply makes sense that the economy should slow and inflation cool as we approach the five-year anniversary of the pandemic, especially in the context of a world economy that’s not all that great. There is no denying, however, that very recent trends are not supportive of this picture. 

Prediction markets

According to cryptocurrency-based prediction exchange Polymarket, Trump’s odds of winning in a few weeks are 60 per cent, while Harris is hovering around 40 — a much bigger lead than the neck-and-neck swing state polls would have you believe. Other popular US prediction markets PredictIt and Kalshi also show Trump ahead, but by a smaller margin.

Are election prediction markets accurate? Early iterations in the US were often on the mark, according to a historical study by Paul Rhode at the University of Michigan, predicting the winner of the US presidential race 11 times out of 15 in the late 19th and early 20th centuries. But election markets have been more or less banned in the US since the 1940s — this election will be the first in decades with tacit federal approval for elections futures exchanges. 

A better way of asking the question is: are the markets more accurate than polls-based models, like those put out by 538 and The Economist? We’d like to believe that markets know better, but the evidence is mixed. In a recent study, elections-betting expert Rajiv Sethi at Barnard College built virtual traders that mimicked the polls-based models, in order to see their profitability relative to other market participants. Sethi found that his virtual traders did relatively well, suggesting that the polls are at least as prescient as the election market consensus.

Advertisement

But as Sethi pointed out to Unhedged, “forecasting accuracy is incidental to the business model” for these exchanges. Stocks’ valuations are supposed to represent underlying value and future cash flows, but are pulled around by hype cycles, market narratives, and short-term traders. Election prediction markets have all that too, and some additional structural problems that could make them even worse. They are not particularly liquid; according to reporting by our colleagues, $30M in trades by four accounts helped swing Polymarket’s US elections market by up to 10 points this month. Plus the market participants are not particularly representative of the electoral base. According to Justin Wolfers at the University of Michigan, bettors on these exchanges are “more likely to be white, male, and Republican”, and the exchanges are not restricted to US voters.  

That does not mean these markets are useless. They incorporate new information quickly. By asking “who will win” rather than polls’ “who will you vote for”, they may also prove a better read of the popular mood. And for traders, they offer a very straightforward hedge to a particularly unpredictable and consequential US election this year.

Due to their structural issues, and because they are still still new, we would not put too much credence in the absolute levels of the election markets in this cycle. But there is clearly some information in these nascent markets, and swings could be good directional indicators, provided they are not driven by just a few big bets.

(Reiter)

Advertisement

One good read

Bhutan.

FT Unhedged podcast

Can’t get enough of Unhedged? Listen to our new podcast, for a 15-minute dive into the latest markets news and financial headlines, twice a week. Catch up on past editions of the newsletter here.

Recommended newsletters for you

Due Diligence — Top stories from the world of corporate finance. Sign up here

Chris Giles on Central Banks — Vital news and views on what central banks are thinking, inflation, interest rates and money. Sign up here

Advertisement

Source link

Continue Reading

Money

Council house building to DOUBLE after October Budget under Angela Rayner’s plans for ‘housing revolution’

Published

on

Council house building to DOUBLE after October Budget under Angela Rayner's plans for 'housing revolution'

ANGELA Rayner is gearing up for a housing revolution, promising to double the number of council houses built.

The Deputy Prime Minister is expected to unveil nearly £1 billion in next week’s Budget to kickstart the construction of tens of thousands of new homes.

Deputy Prime Minister Angela Rayner will be handed a huge cash boost at the Budget

1

Deputy Prime Minister Angela Rayner will be handed a huge cash boost at the BudgetCredit: PA

But the cash boost is expected to be just the start, with even bigger sums expected in next spring’s multi-year spending review.

Advertisement

Ms Rayner believes council housing is crucial for Labour’s target of 1.5 million new homes in the next five years.

Her team is arguing more council homes could slash the £9 billion benefit bill and cut the cost of temporary housing that’s crippling council budgets.

As part of her house building plan, the Housing Secretary is also set to crack down on the Right to Buy scheme, which has seen thousands of council homes sold off at massive discounts.

The Deputy PM wants to drastically reduce these discounts and tighten the rules, meaning tenants will need to live in their homes for ten years – up from the current three – before being allowed to purchase.

Advertisement

For newly-built council homes, the option to buy could be scrapped altogether, preserving much-needed social housing stock.

These moves are designed to stop the steady drain of social housing, with 23,000 homes being lost each year due to sales, demolition, or conversions, while only 11,000 are built.

Ms Rayner is determined to reverse this trend by 2026.

This is despite her buying her council house using the Right to Buy scheme in 2007 with a 25 per cent discount, making a reported £48,500 profit when selling it eight years later.

Advertisement

Backing her plans is Chancellor Rachel Reeves, who has agreed to top up the housing budget with up to £1 billion.

Despite disagreements over local government funding, both Ms Rayner and Ms Reeves appear united when it comes to tackling the housing crisis.

A senior government source told The Times: “Angela’s ambitions on social and council housing have the full backing of the prime minister and chancellor, and that will become even clearer in the weeks ahead.

“They are joined at the hip when it comes to getting Britain building.”

Advertisement

What Is Right To Buy?

RIGHT to Buy was introduced in 1980 by Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher’s Conservative government.

The scheme allows people renting council homes (owned by local councils) to buy their homes at a discount.

The longer you’ve lived in the property, the bigger the discount—up to 70 per cent off.

Advertisement

It was designed to help tenants become homeowners, and millions of people have used it.

However, the scheme has also led to a large reduction in available council homes, as many were sold and not replaced.

This has contributed to a shortage of affordable housing for people in need.

Angela Rayner now wants to reduce the discounts and make it harder for tenants to buy their council homes, aiming to protect the number of affordable homes available.

Advertisement

Source link

Continue Reading

Travel

Norse Atlantic to launch Rome-Los Angeles route

Published

on

Norse Atlantic to launch Rome-Los Angeles route

The thrice-weekly service will start on 22 May, 2025, joining the carrier’s existing seasonal flights to LA from Gatwick, Oslo and Paris CDG

Continue reading Norse Atlantic to launch Rome-Los Angeles route at Business Traveller.

Source link

Advertisement
Continue Reading

Business

China cuts interest rates in battle to hit year-end growth target

Published

on

Stay informed with free updates

China unveiled some of its biggest cuts to benchmark lending rates in years as the government stepped up efforts to reboot the economy and hit its year-end target of about 5 per cent GDP growth.

The People’s Bank of China said on Monday that the country’s one-year loan prime rate would be reduced to 3.1 per cent from 3.35 per cent, the biggest reduction on record, and the five-year LPR would be cut to 3.6 per cent from 3.85 per cent.

Advertisement

The rates have acted as the underlying reference for consumer or business loans and mortgages, respectively, since 2019. They were last cut in July and follow a blitz of easing measures announced in late September that mark the government’s most forceful intervention since the pandemic.

Widely anticipated against that backdrop, Monday’s cuts underscore growing urgency among policymakers to restore confidence in an economy grappling with a property slowdown, deflationary pressures and weak consumer demand.

“Today’s move echoes our view that the PBoC will be cutting rates more decisively,” said Becky Liu, head of China macro Strategy at Standard Chartered.

The September package, which included reduced mortgage rates and support for the stock market, came amid mounting pressure on policymakers to hit a GDP growth target of about 5 per cent for 2024.

Advertisement

Economists have widely called for more intervention, including fiscal stimulus and more support for households. China’s latest GDP figures on Friday showed growth of just 4.6 per cent in the third quarter.

“A meaningful turnaround in economic growth would require a larger fiscal response,” said Zichun Huang at Capital Economics, in response to the cuts.

Monday’s cuts were at the upper end of a range signalled by Pan Gongsheng, PBoC governor, on Friday when he reiterated the prospects of further easing before the end of the year.

In September, he announced cuts to China’s seven-day repo rate, another lending benchmark. The reserve requirement ratio, which influences bank lending, was cut 50 basis points that month, leaving the average rate across banks at 6.6 per cent. It could be cut by another 25-50 basis points.

Advertisement

Liu at StanChart pointed to a September statement from the politburo, China’s top leadership group, on the need to “implement forceful rate cuts”, which were “the first time ever for such precise guidelines on central bank interest rates”.

UBS on Monday raised its full-year target for China’s GDP growth to 4.8 per cent. “Both household and corporate confidence may be helped by expectations of more policies and property market stabilisation,” said the bank’s chief China economist Tao Wang.

China’s CSI 300 index of Shanghai- and Shenzhen-listed shares rose 0.3 per cent in volatile early trading on Monday. The CSI 2000 index of small-cap companies outperformed with a 2.8 per cent gain. Hong Kong’s Hang Seng index lost 1.2 per cent.

Advertisement

Additional reporting by Wang Xueqiao in Shanghai

Source link

Continue Reading

Money

MM Talks Episode 3: FCA Consolidation, Budget Predictions, and Spooky Finance Stories

Published

on

MM Talks Episode 3: FCA Consolidation, Budget Predictions, and Spooky Finance Stories



Join Kimberley Dondo, Lois Vallely and Tom Browne from the Money Marketing team for the third episode of MM Talks! This episode explores the FCA’s consolidation review, and speculation of the upcoming budget’s impact on financial advisers, and shares chillingly true finance horror stories from the internet! Listen now:

Source link

Advertisement
Continue Reading

Business

The Nobel for Econsplaining

Published

on

It’s tempting to think that England was always a seafaring and financial power, but these skills had to be learned, together. That’s why An Introduction to Merchants Accounts by John Collins was a big deal when it was published in 1653.

England came late to the long-distance maritime trade, and so instruction on Italian methods of bookkeeping had tended to be translated from the Dutch. Collins, however, had spent time in the Mediterranean on an English ship fighting for the Venetians, and had learned the Italian methods himself.

The sample journal entries in Collins’ textbook reflect trades that were common in England at the time, the ones he had learned — oil from Provence, soap from Venice, the ginger and cotton that indentured servants grew on Barbados.

By the middle of the 18th century, both the trade and the textbooks had changed. John Mair’s 400-page Book-keeping Methodised became over several editions the most popular accounting textbook in the English-speaking Atlantic world — George Washington kept a copy at Mount Vernon.

Advertisement

Mair still promised to teach both theory and practice “according to the Italian form,” but his new examples reflected the new long-distance trade. A whole chapter of sample journals dealt with Jamaica, Barbados and the Leeward Islands, which Mair called the sugar colonies. He treated Virginia and Maryland in their own chapter, too, as the tobacco colonies.

While British had been teaching themselves Italian accounting, they had also been learning from the Portuguese and the Dutch the tenets of the engenhos, the mill system where enslaved Africans planted, harvested and processed sugar. The transatlantic trade wasn’t just incidental, this for that. The ginger and cotton on Barbados had become sugar because engenhos were much more profitable for their owners. As we can read now all the way down to the textbooks, sugar had become the engine of the Atlantic.

I went back to Collins and Mair this week after Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson and James Robinson won the Sveriges Riksbank Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel. They won for taking on the question of divergence — why some countries have enjoyed enduring prosperity since the early modern period, while others have languished. What made the difference, they argued, were institutions, habits of law and society.

Inclusive institutions that secured property rights and encouraged investment were more likely to produce prosperity. Extractive institutions, which claim spoils for the elite and discourage investment, produce low growth over time.

Advertisement

In Why Nations Fail, Acemoglu and Robinson’s 2012 summary of their work on institutions, they use late 17th century England, Barbados and Virginia as examples. England and Virginia became inclusive: property rights, legislative assemblies, limited but slowly expanding franchise. Barbados became extractive, relying on enslaved labour to produce profits for a small elite.

These descriptions are true but insufficient, because England, Barbados and Virginia were all part of the same system. The same captive domestic market, protected by tariffs, sent slave tobacco and slave sugar through factors in the colonies and merchants in London and Glasgow.

The shape of this captive market was clear to John Mair, who wrote a chapter of instructions on how to account for the enslaved and the sugar trade through factors in Barbados and Jamaica, explaining how that trade “not only employs multitudes abroad in the colonies, but cuts out work for a vast deal of people at home.” Both manufacturers and merchants, he wrote, “are hereby not only maintained, but many of them enriched.”

London merchants and Barbadian planters, well represented in Parliament, became powerful advocates for inclusive institutions in Britain not in contrast to the extractive institutions on the other side of the ocean, but because of them.

Advertisement

It is easy to pick on Nobel Prize winners from afar. If they’re so wrong, it should be easy for you to prove it and claim your own trip to Stockholm. This question of just how much extraction contributed to England’s financial and industrial revolutions, though, is one of the most openly and furiously contested problems of early modern Atlantic history.

It offers another well documented, compelling explanation for the inclusive institutions of early-modern Britain. Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson have encountered this question — it’s right there in their footnotes. They just don’t seem to think it matters.

They are by all accounts nice, thoughtful guys, so the problem doesn’t seem to be arrogance or wilful blindness. Rather, this inability to see how London, Virginia and Barbados function within the same system is, ironically, an institutional problem within the profession of economics.

Economists are really good with numbers. This is important. Numbers matter, and the ability to infer how they affect each other matters, too. Some things, however, don’t seem to respond in obvious ways to numbers, or sometimes the numbers are constrained by things that are hard to measure.

Advertisement

It’s helpful to think of these things as institutions, the habits of mind and the state that shape markets. Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson are right to see the importance of institutions, and they were right to drag the rest of their profession in their direction. The problem is that institutions are exactly the parts of markets that are inherently resistant to discovery through numbers.

Luckily, there are other professions that find, train and accredit the kinds of people who are good at understanding the political and cultural forces that drive institutions. These professions are the rest of the social sciences — sociology, history, anthropology, political science.

Economists are socialised to look down on the rest the social sciences as unserious, but it’s a funny ol’ thing when you reach the end of numbers and bang into an institution. You need new tools, exactly the ones you were told lacked rigour. This week economists have been congratulating themselves on following Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson into institutions. They are, in effect, proud to have discovered the rest of the social sciences.

It would be churlish to gatekeep the economists out. The study of history, for example, is just the application of eyeballs to paper over time. All should be welcome. But it’s reasonable to expect curiosity and discipline, to ask the economists to sit still long enough to encounter all the basic questions lobbed at every first-year grad student. Mastery of these questions is not just a status signifier; it shows that you understand what has already been said, so you can contribute something new and meaningful.

Advertisement

Economists would never dream of approaching the nature of the firm without explaining carefully where they stand on Ronald Coase, for example. But this is exactly what Acemoglu and Robinson do in the opening chapter of Why Nations Fail.

They argue that the Virginia Company began with an extractive model, looking for gold, and then by the 1620s had begun developing inclusive institutions, such as Virginia’s General Assembly, “the start of democracy in the United States.” The footnotes reveal the source to be Morgan (1975). Edmund Morgan published in that year what is still today the single most important book about early colonial Virginia. But the name of that book is, unfortunately, American Slavery, American Freedom.

Morgan argued that the institutions of democracy and slavery in early Virginia developed together, driven by the same events. For about the first 30 years of Virginia’s development as a tobacco plantation, enslaved Africans and white indentured servants were treated with similar disdain, worked together in the fields, often made common cause and even married.

When white Virginian servants started to live longer, however, they rebelled and demanded curbs to the privileges of the big planters. Virginians created their slave code over the same period, outlawing intermarriage, writing a womb law that tied the status of a child to the status of the mother, confirming that slave status was permanent, and discouraging white women from having children with Black men.

Advertisement

Morgan argues that the extractive institution of Black slavery had changed by the end of the century, becoming even more draconian and brutal, as the democratic institutions of colonial Williamsburg became more representative. Inclusive institutions for white Virginians became possible not despite the extractive institution of Black slavery, but because of it.

You don’t have to agree with Edmund Morgan when you’re writing about early America. But you do have to respond to him, in the same way you respond to Ronald Coase when writing about the firm. This is not a niche reading of an old work. It is one of the central theses of the historiography of early American institutions.

Acemoglu and Robinson read a book called American Slavery, American Freedom, used the bits about American freedom and tossed the bits about American slavery. The new economic institutionalists treat work on institutions by a celebrated historian not as a coherent argument, but as a source of anecdotes. If they did this with data, you’d call it p-hacking.

There’s more historiographical p-hacking in How Nations Fail. They quote Sheridan (1973) on conditions in Barbados. But Richard Sheridan’s Sugar and Slavery argues in part that the English didn’t just profit from slavery in the West Indies, they gathered both capital and competence in shipping and finance.

Advertisement

This is not hard to find in Sheridan; he frames his entire work around a late 18th century argument between Adam Smith and Edmund Burke. Smith argued that the sugar colonies had been an expensive mistake. Burke pointed out that the sugar colonies had become a crucial destination for English exports. Sheridan moves this argument forward, all the way to the big Atlantic question of growth.

Neo Smithians, he said, “tend to focus on such indigenous [British] forces of change as science and technology, entrepreneurship, and capital formation, acting and reacting in such a manner as to lower the institutional barriers to economic growth.”

The Neo Burkians saw in the Atlantic empire an “important source of wealth for the mother country,” one that “supported, and in some cases directly financed, the infant manufacturers who launched the Industrial Revolution.” The empire created new wealth, which paid for new landed estates and Parliamentarians who “influenced imperial policy in their own interest.”

Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson are neo Smithians. That’s their right; most economists are. But again, if they’re interested in institutions and they’re going to use Sheridan, why not actually take Sheridan seriously?

Advertisement

You’ll find in Sugar and Slavery an account of the same accumulation of the skills in finance and the trade laid out in John Mair’s textbook. Sheridan offers an uncomfortable origin story for the institutions of British finance, which among other achievements produced the Financial Times. If you’re going to study institutions, you have to be curious about all of them.

This year the Riksbank awarded its prize to a treatment of early modern institutions so selective it functions as a bedtime story for capitalists. The good institutions produced prosperity. The bad ones produced misery.

But good and bad institutions have always been paired. It is not so easy to tease them apart into natural experiments, and just as useful to see how they’re connected. Democracy and the rule of law are the best institutions we have. We should celebrate them and fight to keep them. And they do create enduring economic growth. But the story of how they came about can cause discomfort. That discomfort is just as important as the celebration. Both help us make better policy now.

It is likely that after this Nobel more young economists will follow Acemoglu, Johnson and Robinson into institutions and history. That’s good! More, please! Stop by the history department. Grab a book. But you gotta make sure you read the whole thing.

Advertisement

Source link

Continue Reading

Trending

Copyright © 2024 WordupNews.com